Hitherto not necessarily wholly foreseen constraints on equality

by Daniel on March 2, 2011

The ECJ has ruled that it is illegal discrimination for the insurance industry to treat men and women differently.

This is currently mainly being covered as an excuse to do larf-o-larf items about “weren’t people funny about women drivers in the 1970s! But actually women are safer drivers! Imagine!”. In actual fact the car insurance thing is not that big of a deal since the no-claims bonus swamps any gender effect within a couple of years; all it really means is that nobody will insure teenagers at all, which I count as not necessarily an unmitigated cost. The real issue is pensions.

Women live longer than men. That’s one of the few actuarially reliable things you can say about life expectancy[1]. And so it requires more resources to provide a given level of life expectancy for women than it does for men. (NB: it is easy to get confused about this – remember that “risk” in context always means “financial risk to the insurer” rather than “health outcome or mortality risk to the insured”, and that living for a long time is bad news for the person who’s agreed to pay you an annuity).

Because it costs more to give women a retirement income, you can basically choose two options from the following three:

1) Equal retirement incomes for women and men
2) Equal commitment of society’s resources to providing retirement savings for women and men
3) A functioning pension annuity industry

There are a load of interesting questions about the nature of equality which might be considered relevant to the choice between 1) and 2) (although they might be considered a lot more practically relevant in a society where there was a greater degree of equality in lifetime earnings). I’m just interested to see that for the first time, a major society has decided that 3) is potentially the one to give up on. Edit: Just realised I probably ought to give my own favoured solution – I think it’s fairly obvious that 2) is the one to give up on and we just have to accept that the biological facts of the matter are that society needs to arrange things so that a given woman has a larger pool of retirement savings allocated to each other than an otherwise qualitatively identical man[2]. It’s rather like the number of social and economic consequences that we accept as flowing from the biological fact that women give birth and men don’t. Historically, capitalist economies have implicitly given up on 1), by allowing retirement incomes to be determined by savings out of lifetime labour income.

[1] by the way, don’t hold out too much hope for genetic testing as a silver bullet solution that will give us all individualised life expectancies and annuity rates. And even if it does, those rates will still be better for men as a group than women as a group, so the discrimination problem will still be there).

[2] the concept of “a woman and man who are identical in all properties except gender” perhaps not being terribly firmly anchored in reality, but as an actuarial construct I can probably save it.

{ 47 comments }

1

chris y 03.02.11 at 8:50 am

What induced this Belgian outfit I’ve never heard of to bring a case in the first instance where nobody benefits?

2

Daniel 03.02.11 at 8:55 am

I don’t know, but I think that it might have a lot to do with annuity products being a British thing and not very popular elsewhere in Europe.

3

chris y 03.02.11 at 9:12 am

Ah, so, absent the annuity market, would anybody benefit? I don’t really see how?

4

Tim Wilkinson 03.02.11 at 9:44 am

“The judgment ignores the fact that taking a person’s gender into account, where relevant to the risk, enables men and women alike to get a more accurate price for their insurance.”

1. But then as the price gets more accurate, it becomes less like insurance and more like a savings scheme.

2. Just as arguments based on aligning tax burden with expenditure benefit (e.g. recently tuition fees) defeat the counterfactual-insurance (interpersonal redistribution of the luck of birth) function of the welfare state.

3. Pensions are an income stream which needn’t (and can’t, see above) be based on individual pension pots.

4. something to do with Gattaca

5

Scott Martens 03.02.11 at 9:45 am

Having just written 200 pages on why the reference class problem is relevant to linguistics (and cutting a number of explanitory examples of similar problems in the humanities, like the interaction between American law and statistical models of Nigerian drug mules), I’m actually slightly concerned by this ruling, even though I agree with the general principle “society needs to arrange things so that a given woman has a larger pool of retirement savings allocated to each other than an otherwise qualitatively identical man” because we do have to accept that men and women are, in some socially and economically important respects, different.

Isn’t the whole freaking point of the insurance industry to discriminate? Some actuary, somewhere, estimates the chance of some adverse event happening to a particular individual on the basis of some set of features that are known to correlate well to adverse outcomes, and figures out how much he has to charge you to have a chance at making some money off of you before an adverse event happens? I’m not accusing the insurance industry of racism or sexism per se, but seen from the perspective of the man from Mars, how is that different from not letting black people into your shop because skin color correlates well to shoplifting?

The argument we make against discrimination is that it violates human dignity to be judged by superficial features, and that it’s wrong to make decisions about individuals on the basis of their membership in class when they have no control over the things other members of that class do. But I just don’t see how insurance is even possible without judging people on exactly that basis.

6

Oliver 03.02.11 at 9:47 am

Ah, so, absent the annuity market, would anybody benefit?

Women buying private health insurance. That is, they’ll get equality. The ruling might make men more reluctant to get private insurance, thus making the overall risk pool worse.

7

Omar Khan 03.02.11 at 10:05 am

I agree in large part with what Scott said. However, there is a wider question: what characteristics should be allowed to input into a risk score. Many of the people who complain about the discriminatory effects of insurance markets are the same people who seek the lowest premiums for themselves. We either need an honest discussion on what characteristics we think can input into a risk caluclation – and how that might be justified – or give up the whole notion of risk-pooling and adopt a social insurance model. I suspect most people who discuss this issue would be unwilling to go for the latter option since tehy think it would result in them paying higher premiums.

8

dsquared 03.02.11 at 10:14 am

Isn’t the whole freaking point of the insurance industry to discriminate?

Not necessarily. Pooling risks is usually a lot safer than discriminating against them. In general, when insurers discriminate in pricing, it is not because some actuary somewhere found a great way of doing so; it’s because their customers started discriminating first, by overbuying some kind of underpriced insurance. Nearly all of the data-mining that insurers do is of this ‘defensive’ kind – to identify potential adverse selections rather than to create new risk distinctions.

9

Scott Martens 03.02.11 at 10:40 am

“Nearly all of the data-mining that insurers do is of this ‘defensive’ kind.” I like that better than the way actuarial methods are described in intro to stats texts, but I’m having some trouble seeing how that works. Assume an insurance company offers a policy which pays out a fixed amount at death, and then sells this policy in an auction, where people bid on how much they are willing to pay for such a policy. (Simple models, etc.) Old people and people with serious medical conditions are likely to bid high for such a policy, young, healthy people less. In a free market, they should discriminate among themselves. But, that’s not how insurance policies work as far as I can tell. There is no fixed supply of policies to sell, so nothing compels the bidder who is most willing to pay for a policy — the person who thinks they have the greatest risk of death in the short term — to pay more, since there’s always another policy coming.

Surely, someone, somewhere, is saying “No, you’re 87 years old and you have AIDS. We can’t charge you what we charge a 22 year old Olympic athlete”?

Since I made pretty heavy use of Venn’s “life expectancy of John Smith, the 50 year old Englishman” example in order to explain reference classes to linguists, *please* don’t tell me anything to make me rewrite that section.

10

Chris Bertram 03.02.11 at 10:42 am

I’m dimly remembering the Goodin, Le Grand et al thesis that wartime uncertainty undermined the possibility of insuring against various risks and thereby let to the growth of support for more comprehensive risk-pooling via the welfare state. So is there a case for saying that IF political or legal factors undermine insurance markets (or to the extent that they do) there will be a corresponding and countervailing impetus to make state provision? (Which may, of course, be outweighed by other factors.)

11

chris y 03.02.11 at 10:58 am

(Which may, of course, be outweighed by other factors.)

Under present realities those parentheses seem to be doing a hell of a lot of work. Even if he wanted to, could Cameron get away with using the state to make good deficiencies in the private insurance market for pensions and cars while he’s actively engaged in removing the state from areas such as disability support?

12

Tim Wilkinson 03.02.11 at 11:19 am

Pooling risks is what the insurers can do that the customer (even the perfectly rational and informed one) can’t. Even with an ideal perfectly accurate individual profile (i.e. level of risk is known exactly, based on all relevant individual features), if there is any risk then there is still no guarantee that the payout will match the premiums (minus the vig) over the lifetime of an individual contract (or even of the insuree).

(If it did, that would be pooling risk between timeslices of the insuree – which I expect can be shown to be equivalent to saving/borrowing money as required, if one can make certain wild assumptions about availability of credit, profit rates of insurers,lenders, borrowers, etc. But much insurance is not like that – the payout may vastloy exceed the payees lifetime premium payments).

The way dsquared describes insurer’s behaviour sounds plausible as a kind of market behaviour – as the bookies (should) change theior odds according to the bets they have recieved, ideally so that they can never fail to make a profit – a distributed dutch book manoeuvre. Bu then there is the question of where a price setter kicks that process off.

13

dsquared 03.02.11 at 11:34 am

I should say that from time to time you get an insurer who really believes that they can do underwriting better and make money by aggressively going after particular classes of policyholder that they think are overcharged in the current risk pool – the example everyone uses is Direct Line in the 1980s[1]. But everyone always uses that one for the reason that it’s a pretty rare success story – most fast-growing insurers tend to end up running into trouble of one sort or another, and a surprising proportion blow up entirely.

[1] What about all those other Peter Wood companies? Well yes, some of them are pretty decent businesses. But none of them had anything like the game-changing impact of Direct Line.

14

Ebenezer Scrooge 03.02.11 at 11:39 am

Dsquared argues that most discrimination by insurers is reactive, rather than proactive. I think he was probably correct in the past, but this is increasingly less true, as insurers are getting smarter. Progressive Insurance, for example, is extremely proactive in price discrimination. They view superior price discrimination as their competitive edge. You can see it in their ads, where they promise that they will try to palm the higher risks off on their competitors. And of course, the reinsurance market has always priced proactively.

In the traditional view of the financial services industry, investment bankers were the smart guys, commercial bankers were kind of dumb, and insurers so dumb that they outsourced all mental functions to their lawyers and actuaries. (AIG was always viewed as the exception to this rule.) Nowadays, commercial bankers are mostly investment bankers, and many insurers are getting smarter.

btw, in the States, the big discrimination issue of the day is credit scoring. Insurers think they have found a correlation between credit scores and risk, or at least propensity to file a claim. Of course, credit scores are correlated with many other things, which raises the usual social justice issues.

15

dsquared 03.02.11 at 12:22 pm

You can see it in their ads, where they promise that they will try to palm the higher risks off on their competitors

This is a much more common feature of industry marketing material than underwriting practice, although I don’t know that much about Progressive Insurance particularly. I do know that “credit scoring” wherever it’s been used proactively as a profitability enhancement tool, has tended to end up as a big fat disaster – there were a load of profit warnings in the UK credit card market in the 00s which could be chalked up to this sort of adventure.

(I’m much more cynical about the reinsurance market and think that the observable hurricane cycle is pretty difficult to explain if you think that pricing has all that much at all to do with rationality, as opposed to the tried and true method of “which big player didn’t like its market share last year”. But that’s another debate I think, and “the reinsurance market” is always a bit ambiguous between small specialised underwriters and the big generic risk trades.

16

dsquared 03.02.11 at 12:32 pm

This is a much more common feature of industry marketing material than underwriting practice

viz, for example, “Sheila’s Wheels“, which trades massively on the “women have fewer accidents!” factoid, but actually it doesn’t (because how could it) make any particular use of this in pricing – it is simply a (really, really embarrassing) marketing skin over the underlying esure business, and it prices by type of car and NCB. On average, adult women drivers will get cheaper insurance than average male drivers, but this is because the average woman driver has a better average no-claims bonus.

17

zamfir 03.02.11 at 1:01 pm

Tell me Sheila’ Wheels is a parody. Please.

18

dsquared 03.02.11 at 1:33 pm

Although it does look like something that would be the occasion for a massive bollocking and multiple “You’re Fired” if it ever showed up on The Apprentice, I can confirm that Shelia’s Wheels is a real trading brand of esure plc and thus (via a chain of ownership through Lloyds Banking Group) one of the ways in which the UK taxpayer hopes to recoup some of his bailout cash.

19

Scott Martens 03.02.11 at 2:09 pm

Don’t suppose anyone saw Sheila’s Wheels statement on the ECJ ruling:(http://www.sheilaswheels.com/media/news/EUROPEAN_COURT_OF_JUSTICE_RULING.html)

The second part confirms D^2: “We’ve always insured men, of course, but frankly they usually don’t go for the kind of car insurance that covers the replacement cost of your designer purse.” Since that seems to indicate they aren’t actually offering anything meaningfully different to women drivers just for being women, why complain about how the ECJ ruling will cause “premiums to rise artificially in a way that no longer truly reflects women’s risk as drivers or the cost of their claims”? Becuse they thought they had to say something?

20

sanbikinoraion 03.02.11 at 2:10 pm

Surely if it’s understood that women live on average longer than men then the sensible solution is to increase the retirement age of women to beyond that of men…

21

stubydoo 03.02.11 at 2:21 pm

Under the new law, that Sheila’s wheels idea turns into pure genius. No self-respecting man is going to buy insurance off of a website that looks like that, so Shiela’s Wheels will be able to keep its premium levels actuarially appropriate for women drivers, secure in the knowledge that they won’t have any unsafe-driving male customers to worry about.

Pretty soon we’ll be seeing annuity-selling companies with websites (and retail outlets) specifically designed to repel women.

22

dsquared 03.02.11 at 2:34 pm

Pretty soon we’ll be seeing annuity-selling companies with websites (and retail outlets) specifically designed to repel women.

A new career awaits me …

23

Ginger Yellow 03.02.11 at 2:47 pm

“Since that seems to indicate they aren’t actually offering anything meaningfully different to women drivers just for being women, why complain about how the ECJ ruling will cause “premiums to rise artificially in a way that no longer truly reflects women’s risk as drivers or the cost of their claims”?”

Presumably because their entire marketing schtick (beyond being incredibly tacky) is “we’re cheaper because we insure only women”. If that marketing line becomes a legal impossibility, they’re just one more insurer among hundreds. It’s a bit like Ryanair’s frequent boasts about how crappily they treat their customers, or would if they were allowed to. They must be cheap if they want to charge for using the toilet in a plane!

24

Chris Bertram 03.02.11 at 3:28 pm

Ok … just had a chat with a pensions economist (in the street). From what I recall of the conversation … (filtered through my poor understanding)

1. The ECJ decision has the effect of mandating for one type of financial product what would constitute illegal discrimination for another. I.e. if Tesco offered higher returns to women on for some financial product that would be illegal, but that’s the effect re annuities.

2. The taxation of annuities in the UK is based on a division between capital repayment and interest components which, in turn, depends on an actuarial calculation. That’s now rendered problematic.

3. The ECJ has a history of disastrous judgements re private pensions and often (as in this case) the judges who make the decision all come from countries without private pension industries. Past decisions require that governments guarantee 90% of value of private schemes which introduces massive moral hazard as companies take advantage of insolvency law (pre-pack) to dump their pension liabilities on the state. (Government guaranteeing private debt … reminds me of Ireland.)

4. The real pension scandal at the moment is the Hungarian government grabbing 11 billion euros from private pensions to wipe out (on paper) its deficit. The EU is doing bugger all about this act of state robbery.

Anyone care to correct or elaborate on those points?

25

SamChevre 03.02.11 at 3:47 pm

I can’t comment on 3 or 4, but I’d say one and two are sort-of true, sort-of overblown.

It’s entirely possible to do a unified-table calculation for taxation, interest vs capital, etc; this might require statutory change, but isn’t actuarially or statutorily hard. (Unified-table; same mortality rate for men and women.)

In my observation, it’s generally considered appropriate for societies to decide what characteristics businesses may and may not consider in pricing. I don’t see “you may not consider sex” as a more indefensible rule than “you may not consider race” (which the US has in its regulations.) To say “you may not consider sex” seems acceptable in other contexts where we know it has differential impact.

26

Chris Bertram 03.02.11 at 4:52 pm

Yes but Sam, surely the point is that “you may not consider sex” is being interpreted in a manner which _mandates_ offering higher returns to women wrt to one financial product (an annuity) but _prohibits_ in wrt to another (such as an ISA). And that looks perverse and arbitrary.

27

chris 03.02.11 at 5:09 pm

Pretty soon we’ll be seeing annuity-selling companies with websites (and retail outlets) specifically designed to repel women.

They could hire Larry Summers, I hear he’s pretty good at saying things that repel women.

28

chris 03.02.11 at 5:13 pm

@26: But any product whose return is measured by someone’s date of death is going to have highly variable returns for the individual buyer anyway. Does it really matter if the distribution of actual returns doesn’t precisely match a theoretical calculation? Individuals are mainly going to be concerned about the possibility that they may be in a tail, anyway.

In any case, part of the problem may be sending insurance to do social insurance’s job. Despite the similarity of names, the goals are quite different, particularly in regard to how to allocate the costs.

29

stubydoo 03.02.11 at 7:01 pm

chris @28:

Surely you don’t suggest that governments interested in provision of social insurance should front it themselves instead of mandating that insurance companies provide it by offering actuarially unsound insurance policies.

I seem to remember a fairly recent widely publicised policy debate here in the USA where such a suggestion was thoroughly rejected by all comers from all sides. So it couldn’t possibly be right.

30

chris 03.02.11 at 8:24 pm

@29: Sure I do. There’s a reason Social Security isn’t a savings plan, was never designed as a savings plan, and can’t be converted to a savings plan without altering it beyond recognition, and it’s not just the desire to start paying benefits immediately for people who were already 64 when it passed. People who die younger subsidize the benefits of people who live longer, but this is accepted because they don’t need the money and can’t take it with them.

31

Mr Art 03.02.11 at 8:53 pm

As a man you would be mad to buy an annuity at unisex rates. Aren’t the UK Govt about to abolish compulsory annuity purchase for defined contribution pensions? Can I now, as a man, sue any adviser who recommends an annuity, for mis-selling?

32

leederick 03.02.11 at 10:26 pm

“Since that seems to indicate they aren’t actually offering anything meaningfully different to women drivers just for being women, why complain about how the ECJ ruling will cause “premiums to rise artificially in a way that no longer truly reflects women’s risk as drivers or the cost of their claims”?”

The insurer has to protect itself and those insured with it against ruin.

If you know a copper coin comes up heads 1/4 of the time and pays £1 if this happens you can price the risk at £0.25. If a silver coin comes up heads 3/4 and pays £1 if this happens you can price the risk at £0.75. Someone who only offers bets on silver coins wouldn’t offer anything meaningfully different to someone who offers them on silver and copper coins, as they’d both condition on the appropriate risk, just Sheila’s Wheels doesn’t offer anything different to any other company.

Now, if you can’t ‘discriminate’ between silver and copper coins what rate do you offer? You have to protect yourself against being flooded with bad risks. If you price near the copper risk (receive £0.25/go), and get lots of silver coins taking bets (pay £0.75/go) you’ll be bankrupt and you won’t be able to pay out on some contracts. To guard against this you’ve going to have to raise the prices for copper coins away from the true risk – to protect 100% (against getting all silvers) you’ll have to charge £0.75 to everyone.

You’ll make a nice profit should you insure lots of coppers, this inefficency is good for you and bad for people wanting insurance. But, if you don’t do this, you can’t be sure of meeting your obligations – also bad for people wanting insurance. You can see why people are pissed off, the ECJ has pointlessly caused a lot of damage.

In practice, the inefficiency will crowd out people at the margin: some women won’t drive who otherwise would. Because Sheila’s Wheels have a very gender biased pool of insured, and because they’ll all be facing substantial premium rises, they’re in a tricky situation. There’s a lot of uncertainty: if they price wrong, their pool of insured shifts, or volume falls off, they’ll be in a lot of trouble, at the other end of the spectrum someone who insures only men doesn’t have to worry too much.

33

chris 03.02.11 at 10:27 pm

As a man you would be mad to buy an annuity at unisex rates.

Not if the only choices are to buy at those rates or not at all. Not buying at all leaves you at risk of running out your assets and plunging into abject poverty at 85, if you live that long. Hedging against that sort of thing is what the annuity is *for* — they have negative expected return otherwise (because the house has to cover its overhead).

34

Bexley 03.02.11 at 10:29 pm

2. The taxation of annuities in the UK is based on a division between capital repayment and interest components which, in turn, depends on an actuarial calculation. That’s now rendered problematic.

Not working as a life company actuary I’m not sure exactly how much of a problem this really is but I doubt it is much of one. On a practical level SamChevre points out you just use a set of unisex mortality rates in the calculation.

Another reason I doubt its a huge problem is that I suspect most annuities purchased from insurers don’t even require this kind of calculation for tax. They will have been bought using money from people’s occupational or personal pension plans (which had tax relief on the contributions paid into them and tax relief on most of the investment returns) and therefore income tax is payable on all the payments from the annuity.

The kind of calculation you talk about is, IIRC, applicable only where you are buying an annuity from savings that are not in a tax exempt pensions savings vehicle.

@ Chris:

@26: But any product whose return is measured by someone’s date of death is going to have highly variable returns for the individual buyer anyway. Does it really matter if the distribution of actual returns doesn’t precisely match a theoretical calculation? Individuals are mainly going to be concerned about the possibility that they may be in a tail, anyway.

Well if I extend your argument you could say that age shouldn’t factor into the calculations either then. Because charging men and women the same rates is something like charging a 65 year old the same annuity rate as a 67 year old. Now sure the 67 year old may live another 40 years and the 65 year old only 5 more years but you wouldn’t bet on it and it would still be perverse.

I can almost see someone lining up to try and push through an age discrimination claim now.

Off topic but one thing to note is that due to the way life offices use postcode/size of your pension pot as risk factors, the poorer you are the better the annuity rate you are likely to get. This is due to the massive gap in life expectancy between the rich and poor. One hopes there isnt a judgement round the corner banning this practice.

Finally I wouldn’t be a real actuary unless I added some disclaimers: the views expressed here are my own and not those of my employer or the actuarial profession etc.

35

stubydoo 03.02.11 at 11:03 pm

Indeed, if they’re going to preserve any insurance underwriting of any kind given the new rules that have been handed down, somebody is certainly going to have to call on some powers of moral-distinction-making that exceed mine.

36

leederick 03.02.11 at 11:06 pm

“Not if the only choices are to buy at those rates or not at all. Not buying at all leaves you at risk of running out your assets and plunging into abject poverty at 85, if you live that long.”

It doesn’t. You could just maintain the capital and live off the interest. An annuity’s an improvement on that, but not much of one. You don’t have to misprice much before people will take out bonds rather than annuitise and leave their kids the cash.

37

Joe Heath 03.03.11 at 1:16 am

I haven’t read the ECJ judgment, so I’m curious what their reasoning was. It is worth noting that the U.S. Supreme Court made a similar ruling (City of Los Angeles Department of Water and Power v. Manhart), in the narrower case of employer-supplied defined benefit pension schemes (which are essentially collectively purchased life annuities), deciding that charging men and women different premiums constituted Title VII discrimination. One gets the sense that they would have banned differential pricing of annuities as well, but that the relevant legislation only protected individuals against discrimination by employers. The court’s reasoning was, I think, deeply flawed, but unpacking the problems with it is complicated. (For those with a wonkish interest in this, I have a paper on the subject: http://www.chass.utoronto.ca/%7Ejheath/Underwriting.pdf — discussion of U.S. Supreme Court case is on pp. 9-15.)

Policy on this question is in general a mess. Here in Canada, some provinces (incl. Alberta) currently ban insurers from charging gender-differentiated premiums for auto insurance, while others do not. I remember reading some stats once on the impact it has on the number of women who drive (goes down a bit). And I should say, even though I’m partial to the principle of actuarial fairness in insurance, there are some examples of risk-classification that would make anyone squirm — such as when U.S. health insurers used to increase premiums on women who suffered from domestic abuse (they were more likely to be hospitalized again).

38

Phil 03.03.11 at 8:55 am

You’ll make a nice profit should you insure lots of coppers

Are they really safer drivers, though, or do they just tend not to end up in court?

39

ajay 03.03.11 at 9:46 am

surely the point is that “you may not consider sex” is being interpreted in a manner which mandates offering higher returns to women wrt to one financial product (an annuity) but prohibits in wrt to another (such as an ISA).

If you equate “similar payments for more years” with “higher return”, then the state is arguably already OK with this, because it pays the same state pension to men and women, even though women will tend to receive it for more years. (In fact they also start receiving it earlier! 60 rather than 65 – though this is gradually being phased out.)

40

ajay 03.03.11 at 9:47 am

You don’t have to misprice much before people will take out bonds rather than annuitise and leave their kids the cash.

Citation needed, I think.

41

Myles 03.03.11 at 11:26 am

I do know that “credit scoring” wherever it’s been used proactively as a profitability enhancement tool, has tended to end up as a big fat disaster

Race is probably a factor in the case of the U.S., as it would likely not be to the same extent in the U.K.

Goodin, Le Grand et al thesis that wartime uncertainty undermined the possibility of insuring against various risks and thereby let to the growth of support for more comprehensive risk-pooling via the welfare state

Always thought this explained part of why the U.S. never developed a welfare state in the same way (and Canada’s welfare state has always been more passive than in Europe as well). Also explains the Swiss health-insurance market, and why they didn’t fully mandate it until I think 1994 or something. (The standard American explanation for lack of welfare state is segregation, but I never found it wholly convincing.)

By the way, could the British government do anything about this? The EU is entirely within its right to bollox the insurance industry if it wants, but this isn’t the EU itself and as of right now it looks more like a claque of Missouri judges telling Massachusetts and Connecticut how to run their insurance regulations, when it manages very well on its own, thank you very much. (Boston and Hartford are the traditional insurance centres of America.)

42

Tim Wilkinson 03.03.11 at 2:02 pm

A quick look at the decision suggests that this was the key moment:

30 It is not disputed that the purpose of Directive 2004/113 in the insurance services sector is, as is reflected in Article 5(1) of that directive, the application of unisex rules on premiums and benefits. Recital 18 to Directive 2004/113 expressly states that, in order to guarantee equal treatment between men and women, the use of sex as an actuarial factor must not result in differences in premiums and benefits for insured individuals. Recital 19 to that directive describes the option granted to Member States not to apply the rule of unisex premiums and benefits as an option to permit ‘exemptions’. Accordingly, Directive 2004/113 is based on the premiss that, for the purposes of applying the principle of equal treatment for men and women, enshrined in Articles 21 and 23 of the Charter, the respective situations of men and women with regard to insurance premiums and benefits contracted by them are comparable.

31 Accordingly, there is a risk that EU law may permit the derogation from the equal treatment of men and women, provided for in Article 5(2) of Directive 2004/113, to persist indefinitely.

32 Such a provision, which enables the Member States in question to maintain without temporal limitation an exemption from the rule of unisex premiums and benefits, works against the achievement of the objective of equal treatment between men and women, which is the purpose of Directive 2004/113, and is incompatible with Articles 21 and 23 of the Charter.

33 That provision must therefore be considered to be invalid upon the expiry of an appropriate transitional period.

That makes it look as though the judges would have been more interventionist had they agreed to an indefinite exemption than in fact they were – i.e. that the legislation basically reasonably clearly mandates this result.

Which at least renders redundant the preceding two paras of what looks like gobbledigook that is uspposed to address the issue whether the benefits supplied by an annuity are the same (‘copmparable situation’) despite differing life expectancies.

43

Myles 03.03.11 at 2:30 pm

Which at least renders redundant the preceding two paras of what looks like gobbledigook that is uspposed to address the issue whether the benefits supplied by an annuity are the same (‘copmparable situation’) despite differing life expectancies.

Can you explain in a bit greater detail? This stuff is going to be rather important, I think.

44

Joe Heath 03.03.11 at 3:20 pm

Thank you for the link Tim. The arguments in the judgment suggest that the case was decided on technical grounds, but the advocate general’s submission contains more substantive reasoning (although one does not know how it was received). Here is the crucial bit:

60. That restraint on the part of the Court must be connected with the prominence which the prohibition of discrimination on grounds of sex has in European Union law. Direct discrimination on grounds of sex is… only permissible if it can be established with certainty that there are relevant differences between men and women which necessitate such discrimination.

61. However there is no such certainty precisely where insurance premiums and benefits are calculated differently solely, or at least essentially, on the basis of statistics in respect of men and women. There is then a sweeping assumption that the different life expectancies of male and female insured persons, the difference in their propensity to take risks when driving and the difference in their inclination to utilise medical services – which merely come to light statistically – are essentially due to their sex…..

67. The use of a person’s sex as a kind of substitute criterion for other distinguishing features is incompatible with the principle of equal treatment for men and women. It is not possible in that way to ensure that different insurance premiums and benefits for male and female insured persons are based exclusively on objective criteria which have nothing to do with discrimination on grounds of sex.


This is basically the same as the U.S. Supreme Court’s reasoning in Manhart (“Even though it is true that women as a class outlive men, that generalization cannot justify disqualifying an individual to whom it does not apply.”) There seem to me compelling reasons to prohibit discrimination on the basis of mere statistical association in the standard sort of civil-rights cases (e.g. Bowe v. Colgate-Palmolive), but not in the case of insurance. The requirement that there be certainty (e.g. of date of death in the case of life annuities) is completely incompatible with the logic of insurance contracts. If you knew when you were going to die, you wouldn’t need to buy an annuity, you would just save.

To the extent that there are good arguments for prohibiting risk-classification, it seems to me that they are to be made in a second-best framework. For example, this paper by Walter Bossert and Marc Fleurbaey (“Equitable Insurance Premium Schemes”) is awesome and important: http://www.springerlink.com/index/nmtlm7l5w81r71xv.pdf (gated, sorry). These issues haven’t been sufficiently explored, however, in part because of the insistence that risk-classification constitutes a form of straightforward discrimination (and thus there is no need to appeal to second-best considerations).

45

Joe Heath 03.03.11 at 3:35 pm

Actually, now that I reread it, I see that the U.S. court was worried about statistical correlation for a slightly different reason. The U.S. court was worried that even if being female made one more likely to live longer, some women do die younger than some men, and so would be treated inequitably by a sex-differentiated premium scheme. The advocate general, on the other hand, is worried about there being no objective mechanism underlying the correlation between sex and life expectancy. If it could be shown, however, that some “essential” aspect of being female was related to women’s longer life expectancy, then presumably sex-differentiated premiums would be ok. Thus the worry is that there might be some other characteristic, merely shared by a lot of women, that is responsible for the longer life expectancy, and so it would be unfair to those women who don’t have this characteristic to be charged higher premiums. Construed this way, the argument could be a version of the Bossert/Fleurbaey worry — that not every refinement of the partition need take you in the direction of increased fairness.

46

Tim Wilkinson 03.03.11 at 4:14 pm

Yeah the decision reads to me as though the point is very much limited to using sex per se as an input to the sums determining rates. It doesn’t mandate equality: if some factors more specific than mere sex can be found that can explain (and thus displace the need to advert to) the correlations between e.g. sex and life expectancy, there would be no problem I reckon. But the stuff about specific mechanisms is pretty alien to the whole actuarial project, which is at bottom just about correlations.

(Myles, as indicated, the apparent gobblidgook is the first two paras of this bit:

27 The Council expresses its doubts as to whether, in the context of certain branches of private insurance, the respective situations of men and women policyholders may be regarded as comparable, given that, from the point of view of the modus operandi of insurers, in accordance with which risks are placed in categories on the basis of statistics, the levels of insured risk may be different for men and for women. The Council argues that the option provided for in Article 5(2) of Directive 2004/113 is intended merely to make it possible not to treat different situations in the same way.

28 The Court has consistently held that the principle of equal treatment requires that comparable situations must not be treated differently, and different situations must not be treated in the same way, unless such treatment is objectively justified (see Case C‑127/07 Arcelor Atlantique et Lorraine and Others [2008] ECR I‑9895, paragraph 23).

29 In that regard, it should be pointed out that the comparability of situations must be assessed in the light of the subject-matter and purpose of the EU measure which makes the distinction in question (see, to that effect, Arcelor Atlantique et Lorraine and Others, paragraph 26). In the present case, that distinction is made by Article 5(2) of Directive 2004/113. )

47

leederick 03.03.11 at 9:22 pm

“Citation needed, I think.”

Page 348. http://www.actuaries.org.uk/sites/all/files/documents/pdf/0271-0367.pdf

It’s entirely possible to do a unified-table calculation for taxation, interest vs capital, etc; this might require statutory change, but isn’t actuarially or statutorily hard. (Unified-table; same mortality rate for men and women.)

You can do the maths easily enough. I think the problem actually ‘income’. Economic, accounting and actuarial theory (and the tax man) are pretty much agreed that income is the change in the value of the store of property rights plus consumption. Just because the law insists on unisex rates when selling services, doesn’t mean you (or your insurance company) can ignore gender when calculating subsequent income and profit from the transaction. The spectre is the recognition of day 1 profits/losses depending on whether you’re (or you insure) a woman or a man.

Comments on this entry are closed.