Talking of higher education and athletics, I want to recommend to people that they read Leveling the Playing Field. It’s is a terrific book, and a wonderful model of how to do applied normative philosophy. It pursues hard and interesting normative questions in the context of detailed and careful empirical analysis of the situation in higher education. The philosophy guides, but does not get in the way of, the empirical exploration; it is also obvious that the authors are steeped in the empirical evidence and institutional detail of the area they are investigating. In the areas where I know the empirical literature in detail they consistently introduced me to new, and more up-to-date findings than I had to hand.
The authors take it as read that ‘educational opportunities should be enhanced for those who have traditionally been shortchanged’, and that ‘individuals should be neither helped nor hindered in their efforts at educational advancement by factors irrelevant to the legitimate goals of the educational institutions’. They elaborate the ways in which the already-advantaged gain additional advantages as they pass through the educational system, and then look at the consequences of this for who goes to college and who goes to which college.
Reform is needed to rectify the unfairnesses they identify, and Fullinwider and Lichtenberg defend affirmative action as legitimate but insufficient. They find that standardized tests have a legitimate role in admissions decisions, but argue that the central reforms should focus on closing the achievement gap between low income and higher income students. They argue that highly selective institutions should foreswear legacy admissions and preferences for athletes (which they show to have a huge impact on admissions prospects).
The authors take widening access to higher education as a central goal, and they think we should get a better match than we currently do between merit broadly understood as it must be and admissions. In defending wider access they also assume that a very large proportion of any cohort should attend college. But why does it matter so much that we try to insulate opportunities to participate in HE (at all levels) from the influence of social origins? After all, we accept, however reluctantly, that access to other goods will be so influenced (for example, access to networks, access to gourmet food, access to foreign vacations, etc).
One reason we might give has to do with economic efficiency; a great deal of productive capacity is wasted by the failure to develop it. This is a public good argument: as a society we are better off (economically) if we develop more the productive capacity of our citizens and higher education is an important means to do that. I am skeptical of this argument. The United States has a great deal of productive capacity, and it is overused: most people spend more time working than they should, and less time with their families and friends than they should. We have exceeded the point at which productive growth is a central public policy imperative, and the policy focus on growth and consumption actually results in people living less rewarding lives than they could. Excessive growth (understood as grwoth of production rather than of productivity) is, in fact, a public bad, not a public good. On top of this fact, most workers have jobs which demand less education than they actually have: much higher education is wasted in economic terms. Finally, the productive capacity argument may not support trying to insulate the prospects for HE against the influence of social class background, because the costs of doing so may well exceed the benefits of the additional productive capacity gained.
I think the more urgent reason for widening access and insulating it from social class background has to do with the fact that higher education is not, really, a public good, but a private good subsidized by the public, most of the return to which goes to the person who gets the education. According to the Census Bureau, over an adult’s working life, high school graduates earn an average of $1.2 million; associate’s degree holders earn about $1.6 million; and bachelor’s degree holders earn about $2.1 million. HE also, not coincidentally, influences access to interesting occupations: some are now structured so as to require a four year degree (or a further degree for which a four year degree is a prerequisite). Up to a certain limit higher incomes influence the level of happiness a person can expect; and higher and status and more interesting occupations yield better health states and greater longevity.
Now, we should be a little bit cautious in elaborating the benefits of a higher education. Some of the apparent return to higher education is in fact a return to the kinds of people who get a higher education; some of them would have done as well, or almost as well, without it, because they have, independently of the higher education they receive, saleable attributes. And there is some evidence that the return to HE is falling, at least in some countries, as uptake increases. But many high income and high status occupations simply require a college degree, so at least the benefits attached to those are conditional on succeeding in HE. It is clear that what we are doing in universities is providing people with access to interesting jobs and the higher salaries, increased autonomy, and additional health and longevity that go with them in our society. It seems a bit rich to use public money to provide those who are already more advantaged by birth with access to even greater advantages.
As with any observation about a positional good like education, two policy trajectories are available to the egalitarian (or, as Lichtenberg and Fullinwider style themselves, the egalitarian of opportunity). The first is to equalize access to the good in question and thereby, indirectly, to equalize opportunity for the good to which it provides access. The other is to break the link between the good in question and the good for which it is positional. A carefully crafter tax-benefit system could reduce the extent to which college education provided access to lifetime improvements in one’s earning potential, by, for example, making net wage rates more equal. The Graduate Tax that some have proposed in the UK weakens the link (slightly) by reducing the effective public subsidy for higher education, and shifting the cost of that subsidy to graduates themselves, hence lowering the effective return to HE. (For more comments on the Graduate Tax see my paper on Top Up Fees). Fullinwider and Lichtenberg opt for the first strategy. I assume that this is largely because the second seems less than promising in our political environment, whereas almost everyone pays some lip service to the desirability of widening access. Another reason, though, for preferring the first strategy in the particular case of HE is that, as well as being instrumentally valuable for access to interesting and well paid jobs, some higher education is itself intrinsically valuable (a great deal of what is taught in science, humanities, and social science departments for example). It is better to widen access and simultaneously introduce more people to the good of HE that they’ll enjoy, than to level down, as it were.
What prospects do their reforms have for widening access in the way that they intend? In fact most of their reform agenda is modest: Maintain Affirmative Action; implore selective colleges to foreswear legacy admissions and reduce athletic preferences; and increase tuition subsidies and the availability of loans and grants. Most important, they rightly demand measures to reduce the achievement gap between lower and higher income school students.
Although I agree with most of them I found the reforms proposed a bit disappointing. It is true that closing the achievement gap is, in fact, an incredibly radical goal; one the achievement of which would, in my view, require a complete restructuring of the whole economy and society in a firmly egalitarian direction. But they do not emphasize this fact, and I can understand why: they seek to influence, and not just berate, policymakers. I see a good case for modesty, because in a world in which the wealthy seem to have taken control of everything there’s not much we can achieve. And in some ways my own stance on university admissions is even more modest than theirs: I’m not sure that we should do anything much about them at all.
Fullinwider and Lichtenberg consistently and rightly emphasize that the reason there is so little uptake of higher education by children from low income and working class background is not because colleges discriminate against them, but because there is a catastrophic undersupply of children from low income backgrounds who are well prepared for college at age 17. There is a large gap in academic achievement, however that is measured or understood which tracks social class.
How might we increase the supply of adequately prepared students from low-income backgrounds? One suggestion might be that we reverse the current policy of making public spending on k-12 education directly proportional to how well off the students are, and make it inversely proportional: in other words spend about twice as much on lower income than on higher income school children rather than the other way round. I suspect that the gradual and uneven movement toward this end will continue, driven partly by the provisions of No Child Left Behind. But would this make much difference to uptake of HE? The UK already employs basically this funding arrangement, and it experiences almost exactly the same problem with HE uptake as the US, and much the same achievement gap. The countries which have a slightly less stark achievement gap are those which have much lower levels of inequality and of child poverty than the US and the UK; but, as we know, reducing inequality and child poverty is not seriously on anyone’s agenda in the US. Personally, I’m not very optimistic about school-located attempts to close the achievement gap, nor very optimistic that other effective strategies are on the horizon.
But one thing might be done. The current funding arrangements for higher education are extremely opaque. Basically, the more advantaged your background the higher the public subsidy you enjoy for higher education; and only the relatively advantaged get any subsidy at all (because only they use HE). It is possible that re-configuring and making more transparent the funding arrangements would have an impact on what goes on in schools. If ever parent and every teacher of a low-income child knew that she would get free tuition and a generous maintenance allowance for attending any college to which she could gain admission on a means-blind basis that would be useful information which might alter the decisions children, their teachers, and their parents, make in middle and high school. If we simultaneously removed some of the subsidies which children from advantaged backgrounds enjoy that would help pay for it. Of course, this is not much more likely than that the government will try to tackle child poverty.
{ 14 comments }
Sebastian Holsclaw 05.03.05 at 9:43 am
“It is true that closing the achievement gap is, in fact, an incredibly radical goal; one the achievement of which would, in my view, require a complete restructuring of the whole economy and society in a firmly egalitarian direction.”
It isn’t that radical of goal, but the problem is that at lower levels of education there is great resistance to actually testing the children to see what they are learning if using those tests has even a hint of trying to measure teacher performance. And if you are not permitted to measure teacher performance by linking it to actual learning, you can’t find out if your reforms (whatever they may be) are working. So long as teacher’s unions successfully avoid the ability to test teacher performance, you can’t reform the system.
Alison 05.03.05 at 9:53 am
“the reason there is so little uptake of higher education by children from low income and working class background is not because colleges discriminate against them”
This is frequently asserted, but is it actually true? I think working class youngsters experience overt discrimination, but their experiences are never canvassed. In many cases they never even get so far as to apply to the institution, so how confident can we be that they aren’t put off by discriminatory attitudes?
Laura 05.03.05 at 11:41 am
“If ever parent and every teacher of a low-income child knew that she would get free tuition and a generous maintenance allowance for attending any college to which she could gain admission on a means-blind basis that would be useful information which might alter the decisions children, their teachers, and their parents, make in middle and high school. ”
I think that would help somewhat, but it would have to part of a much bigger project. The HOPE scholarship program in GA, which offers a free ride at a state college for anyone who earns a B or better at high school, has not been successful in increasing the percentage of low income students in college.
Harry 05.03.05 at 3:18 pm
sebastian,
whether it is a radical goal depends partly on how you interpret it. If it is literally *closing* the achievement gap, so that there is no correlation between achievement and socio-economic class of origin (except whatever can be explained by some putative IQ gap that correlates with socioeconomic class of origin) then, yes, it certainly would require a fair amount of monitoring (and hence testing) but it is an extraordinarily radical goal. AT least given the available technologies; we simply don’t know how to get high or even modest levels of academic acheivement from swathes of children raised in relative poverty, for example; so we’d have to reduce the proportion of kids raised in poverty from 17-20% (as now) to 0% (or thereabouts). Resistance to testing is as nothing compared to resistance to eradicating child poverty.
There are other ways of interpreting it: ‘closing’ is often interpeted as ‘changing slightly’ and ‘achievement gap’ is very often interpreted in terms of everyone reaching some (low-ish) threshold of performance.
Laura — yes, I agree it would take a lot more. Is it clear, in fact, that the Hope scholarship program is well understood by all relevant parents.
alison: I guess there might be discriminatory attitudes. What counts as a discriminatory attitude though? Suppose you had a college which deliberately promoted a pro-intellectual ethos. Would that constitute a discriminatory attitude? Not by my standards.
What is sure is that if a kid from a working class or poor background with any level of SAT/ACT, GPA (corrected for quality of school) and AP scores applies to a college they will have at least as much chance of admission as a kid from a wealthy background. (Not as much chance of accepting, or of completing, but that’s a different matter). College administrators spend a lot money trying to find well-prepared low income kids. Maybe if there were suddenly large numbers of such kids available we’d find middle-class parents pressuring to restructure admissions to discriminate against them: in fact, I bet we would. Then we’d find out.
ken 05.03.05 at 5:22 pm
“Fullinwider and Lichtenberg consistently and rightly emphasize that the reason there is so little uptake of higher education by children from low income and working class background is not because colleges discriminate against them, but because there is a catastrophic undersupply of children from low income backgrounds who are well prepared for college at age 17.”
So, the problem is less to do with college admissions practices as it is that the students are prepared for HE. Now you’re talking effectiveness of secondary, or even elementary education.
Harry, you’ve approached the problem from an institutional perspective. I wonder about the view from the other end of the telescope: the influence of culture/subculture and the family. While economics does plays a significant role, public access to education through grade 12, and hence, preparation for HE, is almost universal. Indeed, it’s complulsory.
So what’s the difference? I would look in the home, as primary, and secondly, in the cultural environment. Where HE is not valued in the home or culture,I would expect low rates of HE enrollment. Whereas, where education is highly valued, there is great incentive to overcome even great obstacles to accomplish the educational goal.
To illustrate, the relatively recent homeschooling movement has been studied to evaluate the effectiveness of that means of education. In Home Educated and Now Adults (http://www.nheri.org/modules.php?name=Content&pa=showpage&pid=27), Ray reports on the success of the students, irrespective of income and social setting. The difference here being the highly motivated family. Indeed, all faced the added financial burden of schooling at home, and many conducted their schooling in the face of discriminatory and legal challenges to do so.
While one might expect for these home schooled students to be denied objective consideration for admission at colleges and universities, such is generally not the case. Again, perhaps it’s because these schools recognize and value the preparedness and highly motivated nature of these students.
Sebastian Holsclaw 05.03.05 at 10:46 pm
“There are other ways of interpreting it: ‘closing’ is often interpeted as ‘changing slightly’ and ‘achievement gap’ is very often interpreted in terms of everyone reaching some (low-ish) threshold of performance.”
Umm, ok. If you posit that education deficits which are currently associated with poverty can only be dealt with by eradicating poverty and if you change “closing the gap” to making eradicating the possibility of variation, I suppose you are correct that the solution must be revolutionary. But that is only because you have been a little funny with the terms.
If you believe that not having gobs of money does not automatically mean you are incapable of receiving a good education if it is available and if you set the bar at significantly reducing the gap (say eliminating 75% of it) you could certainly take a stab at it by improving the awful inner-city school systems. But to do that you would need to be allowed to identify how children are doing year to year to sift the good schools from the bad and the good techniques from the bad. And that isn’t going to be allowed so long as the current teachers’ unions have the deciding say in the matter.
Alison 05.04.05 at 1:31 am
if a kid from a working class or poor background with any level of SAT/ACT, GPA (corrected for quality of school) and AP scores applies to a college they will have at least as much chance of admission as a kid from a wealthy background.
That certainly wasn’t what I was told when I applied to college. There weren’t SATs in those days, we just had our A levels, but one would be given a nod and wink regarding Universities which were prepared to consider the application of youngster’s from a non-affluent background. I went to Warwick University, which had such an enlightened policy. I can tell you the ones which had a policy of non-acceptance if you like – I suspect all academic working class children know which they are.
One would also notice that, following admission interviews, white middle class youngsters would be set lower admission targets than we would.
I had a friend who was a Ugandan Asian (so-called, the equivalent of an asylum seeker nowadays I suppose) who was rejected by every University he applied to apart from Aberdeen which required maximum A level grades. Luckily he got that. Meanwhile my other friend, son of a doctor, was accepted into medical school with 3 grade Cs.
It isn’t just the overt discrimination which damages your chances, it’s the feeling of monolithic rejection. The awareness that one is at best tolerated.
I always think that for a working class scholar there is a tightrope. If you are not rebellious enough you will do what all the institutions are telling you to do – go and get a job in a shop, forget about your silly ambitions – while if you are too rebellious you will throw your books in the river and say sod the lot of them.
John Quiggin 05.04.05 at 5:17 am
I don’t think education is a positional good. If more people get educated, it’s true, other things equal, that the wage premium for education declines (supply and demand), but this in turn implies more employment in areas requiring education.
Harry 05.04.05 at 7:17 am
alison – my comments were restricted to the US, so I withdraw them completely concerning the UK, where A-levels are still what they use. I don’t know the literature about this in the UK — except that there isn’t much. I’d guess things are better than they were, in many ways (with 50% HE participation it must be).
Sebastian, I think my use of the terms respects their normal menaing better than the eccrentric re-interpretations. I agreed with you that doing improvements would require a fair degree of monitoring and testing. You’d be surprised how much support there is for this in the teachers unions; AFT for example was a force behind NCLB. The central problem is that unions believe (rightly, in my view) that schools and districts are very poorly managed, and therefore are very reluctant to cede power over these issues to what they see as incompetent and ill-willed managers.
If you know of some literature about how we can improve the achievment of large swathes of poor children I’d be thrilled to see it!
Alison 05.04.05 at 8:37 am
I’d guess things are better than they were, in many ways (with 50% HE participation it must be).
I hope you don’t mind me contiuing to address your points. I think two things to consider are that working class HE participation rates in the US are no better than in the UK, therefore it is likely (to me, speaking as an outsider) that similar institutional barriers are in place, and secondly that in both countries the gap between affluent and non-affluent enrolment has worsened since the eighties, when I graduated, so I don’t think the situation has improved in either country.
I think there is a danger that a particular social class evaluates its own relationship with the less privileged, and gives itself top marks for inclusion – without giving a voice to those who are excluded.
UK gov’t report from 2003 on the drive for widening partipiation in HE:
http://image.guardian.co.uk/sys-files/Education/documents/2003/04/08/Widening.pdf
“Around half of the population describe themselves as (working class). In 2000, 18 per cent of young people from these backgrounds were benefiting from higher education. While this was an increase of 8 percentage points on the position in 1990, the increase in participation by people from families with professional and non-manual occupations was 11 percentage points (from
37 per cent to 48 per cent). In other words, the gap in participation between those in higher and
lower social classes has grown. Indeed, if one turned the clock back to 1960 … the gap between the two groups was actually less than it is now.”
RS 05.04.05 at 10:37 am
“I’d guess things are better than they were, in many ways (with 50% HE participation it must be).”
Not if different classes segregate by institution – which is what they in fact do. So at the top end you get the best of the working class and the best and quite a lot of the rest of the middle and upper classes, at the bottom end you get the majority of the working class participation.
“I had a friend who was a Ugandan Asian (so-called, the equivalent of an asylum seeker nowadays I suppose) who was rejected by every University he applied to apart from Aberdeen which required maximum A level grades.”
I believe it is Asians from a Bangladeshi background that suffer that fate now.
mpowell 05.04.05 at 1:25 pm
Alison- I have a hard time understanding your position on this issue of discrimination against lower class applicants. Anyone familiar w/ the enrollment process at universities in the US would disagree based on anecdotal evidence and Harry has already made the observation that the statistical evidence in the US strongly disagrees as well.
Even the data you quote does not support your position. From 1990-2000 the percentage of young people from working class backgrounds grew 80 percent. Among those from professional backgrounds the percentage grew 29 percent. This isn’t even close. Another way to say it- assuming the ratio of kids from working class backgrounds to professional backgrounds remains constant at 1:1, from 1990 to 2000 the number of working class kids enrolled in HE as a percentage of working + professional kids so enrolled, increased from 21% to 27%. How is this an increase in the gap? Just b/c the absolute difference in numbers is greater?
Harry 05.04.05 at 1:50 pm
Alison, we might be talking at cross-purposes. In the UK it is true that relative social mobility has been fairly constant over time; and despite what mpowell points out I think that the top layer of universities hasn’t experienced much improvement in the proportions of w-c students relative to m-c students. But what you asked about was discrimination, by which I took it that you meant discrimination in admissions. The dramatic decrease in use of interviews has all-but-eliminated one source of discrimination. In the time period we’re talking about (between you and me graduating and now) the income and wealth gap between low and high socio-economic-status households has increased, the old means-tested maintenace grant has been abolished, and my guess is that the schooling of lower s-e-s student has worsened relative to that of higher s-e-s students. My conjecture is that these, rather than discrimination in admissions, account for the lack of progress in getting more equal participation. We must have some UK university admissions tutors as readers: any thoughts from them would be welcome.
You seem to hint at the idea that the ethos or atmosphere in universities is off-putting to w-c students. That may be so. Does that count as discrimination? I don’t know.
Alison 05.05.05 at 3:28 am
How is this an increase in the gap?
My quoted text was from a British government publication, acknowledging that their policies had failed to close the gap. It was a rare example of a government admitting failure, and they had no motive to massage the figures to be worse than they actually are.
The ‘increase in gap’ means that the expansion of higher education participation has been largely an expansion in participation by people from middle class backgrounds. Thus at one time the gap was 27 percentage points and it is now 30.
Comments on this entry are closed.