Bookblogging: Micro-based macro (updated)

by John Q on October 8, 2009

Another installment of my slowly-emerging book on Zombie Economics: Undead ideas that threaten the world economy. This is from the Beginnings section of the Chapter on Micro-based Macro. I’ve now posted drafts of the first three chapters (+Intro) at my wikidot site, so you can get some context. In particular, before commenting on omissions, take a quick look to see that the point hasn’t been covered elsewhere.

Micro-based macro is here

Macroeconomics began with Keynes. [1]Before Keynes wrote The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, economic theory consisted almost entirely of what is now called microeconomics. The difference between the two is commonly put by saying that microeconomics is concerned with individual markets and macroeconomics with the economy as a whole, but that formulation implicitly assumes a view of the world that is at least partly Keynesian. Long before Keynes, neoclassical economists had both a theory of how prices are determined in individual markets so as to match supply and demand (‘partial equilibrium theory’) and a theory of how all the price in the economy are jointly determined to produce a ‘general equilibrium’ in which there are no unsold goods or unemployed workers.

The strongest possible version of this claim was presented as Say’s Law, named, somewhat misleadingly, for the classical economist Jean-Baptiste Say. Say’s Law, as developed by later economists such as James Mill, states, in essence, that recessions are impossible since ‘supply creates its own demand’. To spell this idea out, think of a new entrant to the labour force looking for a job, and therefore adding to the supply of labor. According to the classical view of Say’s Law, this new worker plans to spend the wages he or she earns on goods and service produced by others, so that demand is increased by an exactly equal amount. Similarly, any decision to forgo consumption and save money implies a plan to invest, so planned savings must equal planned investment and the sum of consumption and savings must always equal total income and therefore can’t be changed by policy. Say’s argument allows the possibility if prices are slow to adjust, there might be excess supply in some markets, but implies that, if so, there must be excess demand in some other market. It is this idea that is at the core of general equilibrium theory.

The first formal ‘general equilibrium’ theory was produced by the great French economist Leon Walras in the 1870s. Walras, like many of the pioneers of neoclassical economics, was inclined towards socialist views, but his general equilibrium theory was used by advocates of laissez-faire to promote the view that, even if subject to severe shocks, the economy would always return to full employment unless it was prevented from doing so by government mismanagement or by the actions of unions that might hold wages above the market price of labour.

The point of Keynes’ title was that “general equilibrium” was not general enough. A fully general theory of employment must give an account of equilibrium states where unemployment remains high, with no tendency to return to full employment.
In the simplest version of the Keynesian model, equilibrium can be consistent with sustained unemployment because, unlike in the classical account of Say, the demand associated with workers’ willingness to supply labour is not effective and does not actually influence the decisions of firms. So unsold goods and unemployed labour can co-exist. Such failures of co-ordination can develop in various ways, but in a modern economy, they arise through the operation of the monetary system.
Keynes showed how the standard classical interpretation of Say’s law depended on the assumption that economic transactions could be analysed as if they were part of a barter system, in which goods were exchanged directly for other goods. In a economy where money serves both as the medium of exchange and as a store of value, the analysis works differently. In the standard classical analysis, expenditure, consisting of consumption and investment, must be equal to income for every household and for the economy as a whole, and so, by the arithmetic of accounting, savings (the difference between income and consumption) must equal investment. This equality always holds true, as you can check by looking at any good set of accounts, including the national accounts drawn up for the economy as a whole, originally by Keynes’ students such as the Australian economist Colin Clark (I work in a building named for him). [2]
But, as Keynes observed, savings initially take the form of money. If lots of people want to save, and few want to invest, total demand in the economy will fall below the level required for full employment. Actual savings will equal investment, as they must by the arithmetic of accounting, but people’s plans for consumption and investment may not be realised. A simple and homely illustration is provided by Paul Krugman’s description of a babysitting co-operative in Washington DC, where babysitting credits worked as a kind of money. When members of the group tried to build up their savings by babysitting more and going out less, the result was a collapse of demand. The problem was eventually addressed by the equivalent of monetary expansion, when the co-operative simply issued more credits to everyone, resulting in more demand for babysitting, and a restoration of the original equilibrium.
Keynes’ analysis showed how monetary policy could work, thereby extending the earlier work of theorist such as Irving Fisher. However, the second part of Keynes’ analysis shows that the monetary mechanism by which equilibrium should be restored, may not work in the extreme recession conditions referred to as a ‘liquidity trap’. This concept is illustrated by the experience of Japan in the 1990s and by most of the developed world in the recent crisis. Even with interest rates reduced to zero, banks were unwilling to lend, and businesses unwilling to invest.

Keynes General Theory provided a justification for policies such as public works programs that had long been advocated, and to a limited extent implemented, as a response to the unemployment created by recessions and depressions ( Jean-Baptiste Say himself supported such measures in the early 19th century). More generally, Keynes analysis gave rise to a system of macroeconomic management based primarily on the use of fiscal policy to stabilise aggregate demand. During periods of recession, Keynes analysis suggested that governments should increase spending and reduce taxes, so as to stimulate demand (the first approach being seen as more reliable since the recipients of tax cuts might just save the money). On the other hand, during booms, governments should run budget surpluses, both to restrain excess demand and to balance the deficits incurred during recessions.

At first, it seemed, both to Keynes’ opponents and to some of his supporters, that Keynesian economics was fundamentally inconsistent with traditional neoclassical economics. But the work of John Hicks and others produced what came to be called the Keynesian-neoclassical synthesis, in which individual markets were analyzed using the traditional approach (now christened ‘microeconomics’) while the determination of aggregate output and employment was the domain of Keynesian macroeconomics.

The synthesis was not particuarly satisfactory at a theoretical level, but it had the huge practical merit that it worked, or at least appeared to. In the postwar era, the mixed economy derived from the Keynesian-neoclassical synthesis provided an attractive alternative both to the failed system of laissez-faire reliance on free markets and to the alternative of comprehensive economic planning, represented by the (still rapidly growing) Soviet Union. Modified to include a theory of market failure, neoclassical microeconomics allowed for some (but only some!) government intervention in particular markets to combat monopolies, finance the provision of public goods and so on. Meanwhile, the tools of Keynesian macroeconomic management could be used to maintain stable full employment without requiring centralised economic planning or controls over individual markets.

[1] That is not to say that no-one paid attention to the economic issues with which macroeconomics is concerned: the business cycle, inflation and unemployment. On the contrary, the early 20th century saw the beginnings of serious empirical research into the business cycle, most notably by the National Bureau of Economic Research, established in the US. And there were some important theoretical contributions, from economists such as Irving Fisher. Most notably, the great economists of the Austrian School, FA von Hayek and Ludwig von Mises, produced an analysis of the business cycle based on fluctuations in credit markets that remains highly relevant today. But neither Fisher nor the Austrians took the final steps needed to create a theory of macroeconomics, and the Austrians in particular recoiled from the implications of their own ideas.

[2] In a global economy, savings in one country, such as China, can finance investment in another, such as the United States. But the arguments between Keynes and the classical economists mostly focused on the “closed economy” case where international trade was relatively unimportant.

{ 15 comments }

1

gd wall 10.08.09 at 7:14 am

2

salacious 10.08.09 at 10:19 am

“But the work of John Hicks and others produced what came to be called the Keynesian-neoclassical synthesis, in which individual markets were analyzed using the traditional approach (now christened ‘microeconomics’) while the determination of aggregate output and employment was the domain of Keynesian macroeconomics.”

Are you going to get into Minsky? IIRC, he was pretty caustic about IS/LM and the Hicksian interpretation of Keynes generally.

Just from what I’ve read on CT, you’re stronger on the attack than on the defense. The stuff knocking down EMH/rational expectations/etc is fantastic, but the arguments in favor of (what appears to be) orthodox Keynesianism feel weaker.

3

John Quiggin 10.08.09 at 12:13 pm

Minsky is definitely going to get a run, but, as you’ve noticed, it’s a lot easier to point out what’s wrong with the ideas that ruled the roost for the last 30 years than to describe an alternative in any detail.

FWIW, my general program is Old Keynesianism+Minsky+bounded rationality, but working out how to combine these elements isn’t easy.

4

Bónapart Ó Cúnasa 10.08.09 at 12:51 pm

I wonder if you want to be more explicit about the role of money in driving a wedge betweend desired and effective demand (is this the main mechanism you have in mind, btw, or are there others?).

Neoclassical micro tends to assume a non-monetary economy, which has meant that money has generally been an afterthought when building DSGE macro models – hence the freshwater school’s blindspot about Say’s law. And it means you can’t tell Krugman’s babysitting co-op story – probably one of the simplest demonstrations of where Say’s law doesn’t hold.

ps – am I the only person outside North America to have originally to thought a “babysitting coop” was something to do with a chicken coop?

5

John Quiggin 10.08.09 at 8:30 pm

@Bónapart A good point, and I’ve now revised to cover it.

On the absence of hyphens with “co”, I (like Douglas Adams IIRC) find the word “coworkers” particularly hard to take unhyphenated.

6

Concerned Economist 10.08.09 at 8:44 pm

I am happy to see that the financial crisis has energized the debate about the proper course of economic analysis. I am also perfectly willing to concede that some of what the best macroeconomists had been focused on prior to the financial crisis has been revealed to be less than completely relevant. At the same time, I am more than a little troubled about some of the more dramatic conclusions being drawn from the events of the past year or two.

Allow me to paraphrase a claim which I have heard again and again recently: ‘everything done in macroeconomics in the past 25 years (or since the early 1970’s) is irrelevant.’ This claim is typically accompanied by suggestions that all the answers to the current crisis are in Keynes’ General Theory or in some other dusty text. Often, commentators go on to casually toss whole collections of macroeconomics into the dustbin without really thinking about their rationale for doing so. For instance, in the post above, John Quiggin asserts that the “appealing idea that macroeconomics should develop naturally from standard microeconomic foundations must be recognised as a distraction.” Professor Quiggin provides essentially no argument as to why he believe it to be a distraction, he just thinks it has to go. His assessment might come from the observation that the push towards “micro-foundations” came during the late 70’s and is thus in the irrelevant period.

Despite the fact that these claims and others like them are repeated and embellished again and again, these suggestions are wildly off target. For instance, throughout the 90’s a substantial area of macroeconomics was developed focused on the idea that financial market frictions and credit market failures could be an important factor in destabilizing the economy. Often these theories were referred to as “financial accelerator” theories. The researchers who developed the financial accelerator were not at the fringes of the field. Rather they include people like Ben Bernanke, Mark Gertler, Greg Mankiw, Joeseph Stiglitz, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Anil Kashyap, Narayana Kocherlakota, Thomas Cooley, Jeremey Stein, Frederic Mishkin, John Moore, and so forth. It is worth pointing out that virtually none of the insights from this work is contained in the General Theory or in any other early text. It is also worth pointing out that the models they developed were entirely micro based and explicitly dynamic. (At the end of Paul Krugman’s article “How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?” it seems he realizes that he might have been a bit too hasty – reluctantly acknowledging the contributions of Bernanke and Gertler and others as an “exception.”)

The idea that we need to abandon all of the recent work in macroeconomics is desperately misleading. The notion that macroeconomists should turn away from “micro-foundations” is also dubious. My guess is that the best young macroeconomists in the coming years will spend most of their energy doing research on credit market frictions building on the previous work from the 1990’s. This work -Krugman’s “exception” – is likely the future of the field in the near term. I doubt very much if it will bear much resemblance at all to Keynesian economics.

7

John Quiggin 10.08.09 at 11:42 pm

@Concerned economists – there will be more coming soon, some of it already up at the wikidot site, so you’ll have a chance to respond to a substantive critique. But, I won’t be asserting that “it’s all in the General Theory”, and I won’t be arguing for a wholesale dismissal of everything that’s been done in the last 25 years.

I will say now, that the work of the last 25 years has not proved to be of great value either in warning of the current crisis or in formulating policy responses. Those who saw a crisis coming mostly focused on old-style concerns about aggregate imbalances and financial hypertrophy. And the policy debate has turned, much more, on the validity or otherwise of standard Keynesian arguments and policy proposals than on issues illuminated by DGSE models.

8

Cagliaritana 10.09.09 at 2:02 am

John, I think it is bit disingenuous to call Bob Lucas’s work as based on microeconomics. Representative consumers and the like are not micro-based. They are just the tools to provide a simple, elegant and absolutely irrelevant representation of macro problems. IMHO, Agent Based Modeling (ABM) and other numerical, open form numerical solutions are much better tools. Not elegant, not closed form , not stuff Chicago school can get behind. But they are much better at understanding bubbles and integrating Simon and Kahneman types micro behavior. And they are really micro based.
Full disclosure – my PhD macro teacher was Leigh Tesfatsion – a UMN macro economist who is a convert of ABM (though she taught us the full story, from IS-LM to Lucas, and not ABM). I now work with geographers who have fully embraced ABM.

9

Robert 10.09.09 at 7:19 am

Has Solow and Hahn’s 1995 Critical Essay on Modern Macroeconomic Theory had an impact on the field? I don’t think Vercelli’s 1991 book contrasting Keynes and Lucas had much of an influence.

10

dsquared 10.09.09 at 8:11 am

It is worth pointing out that virtually none of the insights from this work is contained in the General Theory or in any other early text

yes they are! the idea that the financial accelerator literature gives us new possibilities that weren’t ever considered in Keynes (or for that matter, Irving Fisher because the “financial accelerator” is basically the same thing as “debt deflation” in a recessionary context) is really quite odd.

Representative consumers and the like are not micro-based. They are just the tools to provide a simple, elegant and absolutely irrelevant representation of macro problems

I think the issue here is not some much that Lucas and the Chicago School’s macro models aren’t micro-based, but that microeconomics isn’t, not really.

11

Kevin Donoghue 10.09.09 at 10:21 am

Has Solow and Hahn’s 1995 Critical Essay on Modern Macroeconomic Theory had an impact on the field?

Solow refers to it as “Hahn and Solow’s universally unread Critical Essay“, so I think we can assume it hasn’t had much impact. Me, I read the prose; as for the algebra, I took their word for it. But it’s good to have my low opinion of the state of macro confirmed by two such distiguished theorists.

12

Chris 10.09.09 at 2:35 pm

It’s not that the Chicago School isn’t based on micro, it’s that it’s not based on *accurate* micro. It has fallen over and sunk into the swamp because they built it on a swamp.

Incorrect microfoundations are worse than no microfoundations at all because they make you disregard the macro-evidence that your microfoundations tell you is impossible. Therefore, since micro is not yet sufficiently well understood, micro and macro should be studied separately for the time being, and any inconsistencies that arise between them reconciled down the road.

13

JoB 10.09.09 at 4:46 pm

John, that was a great piece! I learned something. What struck me when reading this is a question maybe you can answer. In how far will micro & macro be co-influencing i.e. the need for one big theory (neither micro nor macro) accounting e.g. for choices that are based on the sentiments being exchanged on the public forum on the general state of the economy and so forth? (Pfew, what a bad sentence, sorry for that) A link via the bounded rationality type theory might make something like that expressable in math – wouldn’t it?

14

Roger Albin 10.11.09 at 9:54 pm

A very minor point. The major body of freshwater close to the University of Minnesota isn’t a lake. Its the Mississippi river.

15

sue womack 10.12.09 at 8:41 am

I’m very interested in economics, as I’m sure a lot more people are these days, following the incredible credit crunch, global recession, economic meltdown, whatever phrase one chooses. The fact remains that something has gone very wrong and this would be a fitting time to learn from these mistakes for the future.
A couple of things re. your article.
I find the baby-cerdits analogy you use to illustrate accuracy of the Keynesian model , extreemly flawed.
Firstly may I say that, I believe that micro economics, to be our only saviour now. Keynes ideas about monitarism and a move towards macro economics encourages unnecessary Government and Banking interference, which leads all to easily to corruption of both people and system.
The example you used in support, the baby credits, seems to me was working.
The members only tried to accrue more crdits because they actually WANTED to carry on using the system and reep even more benifits from it, quicker. In other words
they wanted to go out MORE not less.! The fact that apparent demand fell, was immediately eased by improving the rewards, a very simple, easy solution, which achieved 3 things. A return to original levels of demand, the dissappearance of apparant stagnation and the possibility of natural expansion.
The crucial factor being that once they were properly rewarded for effort the whole system RETURNED to functioning efficiently.
If this had been fixed using the Keynesian model they would probably first tried laying people off, lessening reward, taking a cut, amassing credits, dishing them back out when they saw fit, hiring outsiders to ease the immediate problem, loosing track of where the hell they were and abondon all the parents and children when it all went wrong.! Sound familiar?
Also you make no mention of Nobel Prize winner Fredrich Hayek whos contribution “Road to Surfdom” written in 1944 reads like a description of how to get into the present day “global financial crisis”, if we follow Keynes to any large degree.
A shame no one heeded the warning then and its to be hoped his ideas will not be so thouroughly ignored this time round.

on using

Comments on this entry are closed.