Quinn Slobodian’s new book, Crack-Up Capitalism is an original and striking analysis of a weird apparent disjuncture. Libertarians and classical liberals famously claim to be opposed to state power. So why do some of them resort to it so readily?
In his previous book, The Globalists, Quinn argued that globalization was poorly understood. It wasn’t – as Polanyians thought – a simple triumph of the market. Instead, it was the partial victory of Hayekian constitutionalism, embedding rules at the global level that prevent democracies or other states from interfering with the catallaxy that Hayek sees as the wellspring both of liberty and economic discovery. The rules of organizations such as the WTO or the European Union shared many characteristics with the Hayekian vision, although they couldn’t fully be reduced to them.
Crack-Up Capitalism doesn’t start from the world of ideas or international organizations, but it too shows how market making depends intimately on institutional politics. It argues that international politics has been quietly transformed by the creation of thousands of “zones,” which are carved out of ordinary regulatory structures. These zones are the product of state policy, and of the willingness of many libertarians (as in The Globalists to embrace rigid state constraints in order to curtail democracy.
The book starts with the musings of Peter Thiel, who notoriously announced in a Cato Unbound seminar that he “no longer believe[d] that freedom and democracy are compatible.” Thiel proposed that the “great task” for libertarians “is to find an escape from politics in all its forms,” and that the best way to do this was to “increase the number of countries.” Quinn argues that Thiel’s stance is not an aberration. There are a lot of people who believe that the politics of Snow Crash – franchise government, and the traditional state shrunk down to a pathetic cult of bureaucratic true believers – sound positively utopian. The result has not just been the exotic plans to set up Galt’s Gulch on atolls and abandoned offshore fortresses documented by people like Raymond Craib, but quieter, more boring-seeming, and ultimately far more important efforts to create special zones that are exempt from ordinary rules and regulations. Crack-Up Capitalism says that there are over 5,400 such zones in the world today. We don’t pay much attention to them – there is no developed international relations literature on them for example, even though they arguably have large-scale implications for international politics. Crack-Up Capitalism explains why we should take notice.
The beau ideal of the zone is a small geographic area with curtailed or non-existent democracy. In 2022, the Simon Fraser Institute’s rankings of the world’s ‘freest economies’ announced that Hong Kong and Singapore were number one and number two respectively, “as usual.” This came after the introduction of the notoriously draconian “National Security Law” in 2020 (which in fairness, the Simon Fraser Institute noted briefly had possibly contributed to a fall in Hong Kong’s overall score – still number one, but maybe not quite as number one as in the past). This high acclaim for a regime that is brutally hostile to civil liberties, and has never had a genuine democracy, says that there is something weird happening in libertarianism.
Crack-Up Capitalism suggests it has been happening for a long time. Libertarians have been fascinated by the Hong Kong and Singapore models for decades. Milton Friedman proclaimed in 1990 that the “right model” for Eastern Europe was not the democratic states of the West, but Hong Kong. Hong Kong provided the model for Deng Xiaoping’s program for making Shenzhen province into a deregulated economic “zone,” and launching the remaking of the Chinese economy, without any significant move towards democratic rights. Notably, it wasn’t only authoritarian governments that wanted to build Hong-Kong type zones. In the UK, Geoffrey Howe, the shadow-chancellor of the exchequer for Margaret Thatcher, turning UK inner cities into “Crown colonies” like Hong Kong, liberated from regulation, so that free markets could let rip. Thatcher’s house intellectual, Keith Joseph wanted to make parts of the UK places where “the Queen’s writ does not run,” eliminating tax, labor laws and health and safety regulations. When Thatcher came to power, eleven “enterprise zones” were created. They didn’t work very well, but they provided a model for Canary Wharf, and the recreation of London as a city where developers could get their way. Slobodian stresses that this was not a fight between the government and the market, but a bitter dispute over two different understandings of the state, one centered around Thatcher, and the other, the socialist friendly Greater London Council (GLC), which the Thatcher government abolished. “Thatcher’s government and the GLC were both part of “the state.” Where they differed was in their conception of what the state was for” (48).
Crack-Up Capitalism goes on to explain how this notion of deregulated zones has colonized the world. When apartheid South Africa created Bantustans like Ciskei, the idea was to create an “African Hong Kong,” an “Export Processing Zone,” with fewer and laxer regulations and taxes. Leftover countries from the era of European state consolidation like Liechtenstein found a new business model, helping rich people in other countries avoid taxes. The Liechtenstein chapter is worth the price of the book alone, describing how its Hayek-worshipping ruler, Prince Hans-Adam, engineered a referendum that allowed him to put forward and veto bills and dissolve parliament – but also allowed Liechtenstein’s communes to succeed (originally, he wanted individual citizens to be able to secede if they wanted). The capital of Dubai and the United Arab Emirates is now less an ordinary capital city than “part of the tool kit for assembling legal modules inside nations, a piece of patchwork that could be lifted up and set down anywhere” (179). And Silicon Valley is, of course radicalizing this ideology, from Underground Man cosplay fetishists like Curtis Yarvin (who I was recently delighted to discover had denounced Crooked Timber in his Mencius Moldbug days), to Balaji Srinavasan’s terribly written musings on the forthcoming victory of the “Network State.”
The book provides copious evidence that many libertarians have a deep regard for the anti-democratic aspects of the state. It emphasizes how a set of projects that claim to promise an escape from politics do anything but that: “No matter the rhetoric, zones are tools of the state, not liberation from it” (236). The concept of the zone encompasses Saudi Arabia’s proposals to build linear cities in the desert. It’s a version of authoritarian politics under which urban developers take on the role of philosopher-kings. It’s no surprise that Donald Trump was an early champion of zones, which gave him millions in tax breaks. Two months ago, the Washington Post ran a story on how some Trump allies:
give him credit for what they see as a bold new idea. One campaign adviser compared the proposal’s ambition to the “Opportunity Zones” economic incentives in Trump’s 2017 tax legislation, scaled up to emulate historic Republican achievements such as Abraham Lincoln’s Homestead Act and Dwight D. Eisenhower’s Interstate Highway System. “There is this broad recognition that we don’t build enough things in America and that, you know, obviously, we have great American cities, but we haven’t really built a new model city,” said Sen. J.D. Vance (R-Ohio), who has endorsed Trump’s presidential bid. “There are a lot of other countries that are trying different approaches out, and I think it’s fine for us to think about doing that here, too.”
Crack-Up Capitalism isn’t just a critique of the right. Slobodian’s arguments hint too that there is a dark side to Yimbyism, which is no more and no less than an alliance between the state and development interests to push past local objections. When he describes the Hong Kong model of “administrative absolutism” as one where “appointed officials and representatives of big business made the decisions with no input from ordinary residents” (46), he provides reasons to worry that big sweeping proposals to do away with local vetos can have a very obvious failure mode. Maryland’s Democratic senator Ben Cardin has threatened retaliation against the left-wing government in Honduras, which wants to withdraw from a system of ““Economic Development and Employment Zones” … where private investors have outsized power to shape labor laws, judicial systems, and local governance. These zones have garnered fierce opposition in Honduras for undermining the basic tenets of democracy.”
But libertarians are likely to see themselves as the main intellectual targets of Slobodian’s book. They have some grounds to protest – not all of them are as hostile towards, or indifferent to democracy as the people described in the book. There is an important Ostromian strain of thinking that runs counter to the strains that he emphasizes, and people will argue over whether Milton Friedman was as unequivocally enthusiastic for restrictions on democracy as Slobodian suggests. Where that possible counterblast crashes into its own limits, is that Milton Friedman is no longer, for obvious reasons, directly engaged in libertarian debate. Peter Thiel, on the other hand, very definitely is, and is arguably the single most prominent figure in the libertarian extended universe right now, less because of the quality of his ideas, than the quantity of readies he is willing to put behind them. As the book emphasizes, there is a lengthy tradition behind him, as well as a consistent demonstrated pattern of libertarians striking deals with autocrats, motivated by a disdain for the messiness of political bargaining, and a desire to put the muscle of the state behind economic freedom. Chile is only one notorious example.
There are flaws to the book. It’s aimed at a popular audience, and hence over-simplifies (I’m about to be guilty of the same, in my own book with Abraham Newman). Too many things are lumped together under the book’s broad argument. Does libertarian rhetoric about the “soft secession” of suburbs justify their inclusion as part of the phenomenon? Maybe – but there is a point at which the argument may be stretched too far. How do zones vary? Are some more successful (however you want to construe success) than others? In non-democratic countries, is it better or worse to have zones like Shenzhen or the proposed Saudi cities than straight totalitarianism? One of the great things about The Globalists was that it grappled with the counter-arguments, and acknowledged where they might have force. I would have liked more consideration of whether there is something important about institutional experimentalism and utopianism amidst the wallops, maybe along the lines of the scattered comments in this piece China Mieville did way back.
But this is still a very sharp and very strong book, which uncovers something important. I recommend it highly, and if I have the chance in future, I’ll be teaching it.
{ 19 comments }
Chris Holland 06.01.23 at 6:31 pm
Libertarianism is inherently opposed to democracy and it must be. Libertarianism is just dressed up corporatism, and the end goal is to concentrate power amongst a small, homogenous in group.
Letting the out group have a say in governance, whether through direct democracy or the republic allows the out group to, somewhat, dictate terms to the few in the in group. People in general want protections from corporations or people in power and when given the chance, they generally vote for candidates who promise to protect them or put limitations on the behavior of corporate actors.
There is a reason libertarians are overwhelmingly white men. The allure of a political ideology that increases the power exponentially of corporations and individuals who already have quite a bit is only going to be attractive to people like Thiel, who have a ton of power, or your rank and file libertarian who believes that their power would increase in a libertarian society. It’s a lot easier to not care about pollution in a river when you have your water flown in from Fiji.
Tim Worstall 06.01.23 at 7:23 pm
” In 2022, the Simon Fraser Institute’s rankings of the world’s ‘freest economies’ announced that Hong Kong and Singapore were number one and number two respectively, “as usual.” This came after the introduction of the notoriously draconian “National Security Law” in 2020 (which in fairness, the Simon Fraser Institute noted briefly had possibly contributed to a fall in Hong Kong’s overall score – still number one, but maybe not quite as number one as in the past). This high acclaim for a regime that is brutally hostile to civil liberties, and has never had a genuine democracy, says that there is something weird happening in libertarianism.”
That’s a bit of a switch there. Free “economy” and free “society” are not the same thing. I have long, vocally, insisted that Mainland China is one of the world’s most vicious free market economies. At least below the level of the SOEs it is. One direct experience was that in my trade at the time (one of the rare earths) a contact in China was able to go from idea to production in less time than it took me to get the environmental permits to do much the same thing here in Europe.
Note that I am not insisting that China is better because of this. Nor am I trying to even imply that the economics makes up for the politics. What I am saying is that the vicious competition of free markets bites harder at that not top level in the Chinese economy than it does here. It is, well, more free market.
Which is also what Fraser Inst is saying, isn’t it? Free market, not free society?
“When apartheid South Africa created Bantustans like Ciskei, the idea was to create an “African Hong Kong,” an “Export Processing Zone,” with fewer and laxer regulations and taxes. ”
Good grief, it was to deny blacks citizenship of SA so that even if votes for all had to be granted then it wouldn’t make any difference. That then – only then – Ciskei tried to go the freeport route is, well, what else could they do?
steven t johnson 06.01.23 at 7:29 pm
DeSantis vs. Disney! On the one hand, corporate libertarians with special privileges over the people of the Reedy district and on the other, a noble hero of Florida fighting for the people’s rights? On the one hand, a fair contractual arrangement, win-win, between a giant corporation and the local people and on the other hand, Governor Gleichschaltung disposing of special privileges to enlist said corporation in his campaign? The first seems to fit Slobodian’s framing while the second is the more orthodox liberal version. The second seems wrong to me but the first seems wronger.
In general, the trend seems to be a triumphalist projection.
If the US manages to bring about a war for the South China Sea—which is the policy goal so far as I can tell—the economic freedoms of both Singapore and Hong Kong and the SEZs will look very different rather quickly I think. Not sure the book will age well.
US Libertarianism’s dubious relationship to liberty has been blatant I think since the days of Lysander Spooner, who “advocated” abolition of slavery by individual violence (no idea why private charity buying all the slaves wasn’t the plan) while later condemning the federal government for tyrannizing over the slaver states by denying their freedom to leave the Union. Or it’s general conjoined twin status with “states’ rights” ever since the days of the Kentucky and Virginia resolutions.
Alex SL 06.01.23 at 10:13 pm
Sounds like an interesting book, but the central idea isn’t exactly new or particularly insightful. Of course markets can only be maintained by state power, and of course libertarian goals are at odds with democracy, and many libertarians are quite openly saying so, e.g., fearing that that politicians will buy votes by promising goodies to the voters that have to financed through higher taxes on the “value creators”.
(The fact that the last few decades have seen nominal democracies enact repeated cycles of austerity and decreases in the top marginal tax rate does not change their view at all, of course, because it is not about aligning beliefs with observable reality, it is largely a paranoid instinct of “I got mine, and I don’t want to share”.)
At the theoretical level, the central equivocation is of the term ‘freedom’. When they use that word, a libertarian doesn’t think of the freedom of people in general to live unencumbered lives and then work backwards from there to policies that maximise such freedom, they specifically think only of the freedom of owners of money and property to use those possessions in the way they want, even if that use harms others.
To be fair, that last part needs a qualifier: as long as it isn’t using a weapon to kill others directly and instantly. Even objectivists are against that, I understand, despite Rand’s revenge fantasies where suffocating young children is justified in a novel because their mother works for the government or something. But obscenely rich people causing harm through monopolising limited resources, applying their stronger negotiating power to force poorer people into humiliating conditions, neglecting to maintain rental properties, withholding emergency assistance, excluding poor people from access to basic services like health care or higher education, or causing environmental destruction is totally fine to libertarians. That may sound like a rant, but it is merely describing what libertarian means in our contemporary context: if all of this wasn’t okay with them, if they wanted to restrict the power of the wealthy and of “the market” to maximise poor people’s freedom, they would not be libertarians but social democrats, AKA “liberals” in the USA. There may be some confused people calling themselves libertarians who are different, but they are negligible in terms of numbers.
All of this is long and well understood, right?
LFC 06.01.23 at 11:18 pm
I rarely agree w Tim Worstall on anything, but I think he’s right on the bantustans: afaik, the main motive for SA setting them up was not economic.
Dr. Hilarius 06.02.23 at 4:26 am
I’m sure the book is of value in its detail but the central idea, that libertarians don’t have much use for anybody’s liberty but their own, has been obvious for decades.
Some here at CT have used the term “propertarian” as a more accurate label than libertarian. Propertarians are fine with state authority and violence in defense of their property interests. Their objection is to having their exploitation hindered.
Fake Dave 06.02.23 at 8:20 am
I was with Stephen Johnston on failing to find any heros in the Florida money swamp, but then he lost me again on the South China Sea stuff. I see the US vacilating between the traditional “strategic ambiguity” on defending Taiwan and a somewhat more confrontational strategy of gathering allies and reinforcing existing military partnerships. If you squint a little, you can even see something that looks like “containment,” with all the hypocrisy and opportunism that implies. What I don’t see is any concerted plan to push the status quo maritime boundaries or start a war with China.
Meanwhile, China’s newly empowered dictatorship keeps pushing the envelope on military “exercises” in the Straits and is openly planning to conquer and annex Taiwan within the next few years. Is it all just talk like we’ve heard before? Maybe. Has the US made themselves a compelling foil for stoking nationalist outrage? Definitely. Will this all blow over as another war of words? I really hope so. Consider though that Xi is about as well established now as Putin was when he started slicing off bits of neighboring countries. Then recall how how quick people were to engage in both-sidism, talk of NATO “provocations” and earnest invocations of Russia’s strategic necessities in their “backyard.”
Some figures on the authoritarian left and right still don’t see the problem with that and will be defending China’s “right” to superpower status the same way, but we’ve been here before and should always consider the risk that the belligerent dictator might actually start the war he’s constantly threatening, whether or not he’s been provoked. If so, all this talk of the US pushing for war will age about as well as all the articles from January 2022 saying Russia’s invasion plan was a western hoax.
MFB 06.02.23 at 9:38 am
The purpose of setting up the Ciskei was to split the overly large (and overly pro-ANC) amaXhosa tribe into two halves which would, it was hoped, conflict with each other.
However, this meant creating an obviously unviable “state” without any of the natural resources which Bophuthatswana, Transkei and Venda possessed, while lacking the tribal legitimacy which a fragmented entity like Kwazulu possessed. As a result, the Sebe regime was inherently unstable and dependent on violence for survival. (I had some dealings with the wife of the late Colonel Guzana, Sebe’s chief of secret police, who would have been perfectly at home in Duarte’s El Salvador.) Guzana was eventually murdered by Sebe’s successor, Brigadier Gqozo.
So where to get legitimacy from? Obviously not from the inhabitants, who were almost invariably opposed to the dictatorship. White South Africans all thought of the Ciskei as a joke. However, white South Africans tended towards libertarianism — especially the english-speakers, who were opposed to the Afrikaner political oligarchy and therefore pressed for an English corporatest counter-oligarchy. So it was possible to appeal to white South African support by pretending that the Ciskei was some kind of liberty-loving haven, where there would be no trade unions (black unions having been made legal, though heavily restricted, four years before the Ciskei gained “independence”) and no nasty limiting laws. Indeed, the Ciskei became something of a haven for white draft-dodgers for a while, and also for whites looking for african whores without the annoyance of white police out to bust them under the Immorality Act, which still nominally prevailed back then.
The U.S. Republican Party bought into this and promoted the Ciskei for a while, as Thomas Frank pointed out in The Wrecking Crew. However, it was never anything other than a pack of lies to deceive the ignorant masses.
I suspect that the same is true of the propaganda around Thiel and the rest of them, but I wouldn’t object to scanning Slobodian’s book sometime, if it ever turns up in our increasingly text-free South Africa.
Ebenezer Scrooge 06.02.23 at 8:48 pm
I think that libertarianism at its best is not so much inimical to democracy as it is inimical to ongoing democratic process. The libertarian mind (again, at its best!) is an intensely constitutional mind: get the ground rules right, and the system can run itself forever without change. Libertarianism wants to push all subsequent haggling and struggle out of the state forever. The libertarian state become a neutral rules enforcer, with the rules all having been worked out in advance: maybe even democratically.
Having done some legislative drafting in my time, I have some sympathy for this mindset. Having also done some legislative interpretation, my sympathy is limited. And finally, have dealt with too many people who call themselves “libertarians,” I don’t think much of actually existing libertarian thought.
steven t johnson 06.03.23 at 12:52 am
Tim Worstall@2 “That’s a bit of a switch there. Free ‘economy’ and free ‘society’ are not the same thing.” If this is an equivocation, the OP copied it from the larger majority of libertarian/liberal writings and discourse. I suppose one could claim a dialectical unity between a free economy and a free society, so that if the economy isn’t free you are treading the road to serfdom. But I don’t think even a dialectician can claim this but simultaneously insist a free economy doesn’t mean a free society. That’s the sort of thing that gives dialectics a bad name, I think.
Besides, security of property has long been the greatest prerequisite for “freedom.” The libertarian vision of freedom is the right to buy or sell anything and everything you can afford, then do what you want with it. At least that’s the version taught while you are standing on one foot. All the rest is commentary.
John Q 06.03.23 at 3:59 am
In Australia, the histories of zones like this have ranged from fiasco to farce. We had one in the Northern Territory which withered on the vine and was eventually scrapped. I was involved in researching another proposal in Townsville (North Queensland) which never got off the ground. And there was a resort complex, initially proposed as an enclave for Japanese tourists, in Yeppoon, central Queensland (it was bombed by an irate opponent, went ahead as an ordinary tourist venture, and shut down a few years back).
The farcical element was supplied by the proposal for a “MultiFunction Polis” in South Australia. No one every worked out what this was supposed to be, and the idea was quietly buried.
When I looked into international experience these zones, I got the impression that they were a stalking horse (or, if you prefer, social laboratory) for the application of neoliberal reform more generally. That is, the idea was to demonstrate success on a small scale in the hope that more and more zones would be created, until the entire country adopted the rules of the zone.
Chris Bertram 06.04.23 at 5:57 am
Particularly interesting to read this post after visiting Gdansk, as I just did, since it was the location of the Free State of Danzig in the inter-war period. There’s quite an interesting little private museum there, which gives the impression that its special status was the basis for a great deal of economic activity free of the constraints faced by both Weimar Germany and inter-war Poland. The Tangier International Zone was in some ways a similar artefact. I wonder if Slobodian discusses either case?
J-D 06.04.23 at 12:56 pm
Russia didn’t need any landing craft to invade Ukraine; China would need a lot of landing craft to invade Taiwan, and if it doesn’t have them then no invasion will happen.
both sides do it 06.04.23 at 8:36 pm
Tangentially related re: private land grabs, sovereignty, and democratic remedies
John Q 06.05.23 at 8:57 pm
Taking J-D a bit further, Russia was able to invade by land, but intended to invade by sea as well. The Ukrainian navy was destroyed on Day 1, and it was expected that the much-feared Black Sea Fleet would support amphibious attacks on cities like Odessa. Here’s a typical story from March 2022
https://www.theguardian.com/world/2022/mar/15/fortress-odesa-city-falls-silent-as-fearful-residents-await-russian-advance-ukraine
Instead, the Ukrainians sank the Moskva, and the BS fleet went back to port. A Chinese assault on Taiwan would be orders of magnitude more difficult
https://insidestory.org.au/why-an-invasion-of-taiwan-would-fail/
Neil 06.07.23 at 5:49 pm
Great piece.
Just a note that Simon Fraser University is a public university (named after a fur trader) and the Fraser Institute is right-wing think tank (named after a river).
roger gathmann 06.08.23 at 8:17 am
And no mention of the Talking Heads song, Listening Wind, from 1982, with the verses:
Mojique buys equipment in the market place
Mojique plants devices in the Free Trade Zone
He feels the wind is lifting up his people
He calls the wind to guide him on his mission
He knows his friend the wind is always standing… by
Fake Dave 06.08.23 at 9:51 am
I don’t want to start a derail about Chinese landing craft. I’m not knowledgeable and it’s barely relevant. It does seem like a country with a huge industrial base and growing navy and airforce could come up with something though. Even terrible, unfeasible plans can still be good for starting wars (which is also a problem with containment). Putin’s plan was a deranged fantasy, but he’s still going for it. The US position in Vietnam was untenable practically from the start, but it took at least a decade of escalation for the generals to accept that they weren’t winning (some never could). China is very serious about being a “superpower” now. Why wouldn’t they start overestimating themselves like one? Hell, they invaded Vietnam too.
John Q 06.08.23 at 7:09 pm
Fake Dave: A three-week punitive expedition (successful incursion, followed by voluntary withdrawal) forty years ago doesn’t seem like great evidence of expansionism.
As you say, it’s impossible to rule out governments starting wars they are bound to lose. But as you also say, the US has a pretty bad track record in this respect. And the military on both sides has a strong incentive to keep confrontation going on. If a war does break out in the SCS, it will probably arise from an incident where both sides blame the other and escalate.
Comments on this entry are closed.